Guest Post
Background
My
name is Abu Haimi. I have been a supporter of the SNP since 2003 and I am now a
paid up card-carrying SNP member (probably the only one in Malaysia). I could
explain why I support the SNP and Scottish independence but I’d like to reserve
that for another guest post (I hope).
I
remember how disappointed I felt when the SNP failed to win a majority in the
2003 election and the euphoria when they became the biggest party in the third
Scottish Parliament. My conviction in the SNP was affirmed in the 2011 election
and I believe this conviction was shared during the Independence Referendum and
the 2015 UK General Election.
Scotland
now is at the crossroads on how to proceed as a nation, within or out with the
UK. The SNP must truly understand the gravity and the burden of responsibility
they are carrying; the entire nation and its people are on its shoulders.
I
am compelled to write because of 9 June TNS poll which showed the support for
Scottish Greens being enough to elect 10 members of Scottish Parliament. There
is misconception being peddled around; it is possible to split the constituency
and regional/list votes, resulting in more Scottish Greens being elected to the
Scottish Parliament. It is erroneous at the very least to believe that tactical
voting will allow this because of the complexity of the Scottish electoral
system. Additional Member System is not as straightforward as
First-Past-The-Post voting system and employs a series of calculations that
must be fully understood and appreciated. I intend to elucidate of this matter
so this confusion can be cleared off.
I
begin my argument by reminding voters (particularly the SNP ones) that all of
these were possible because voters chose and kept continuously voting for the
SNP in every election. The mandate allowed them to carry out and implement
their policies, the ultimate one being the Independence Referendum. Therefore,
crux of my argument is that voters should always vote for the
parties/manifestoes they believe in.
The Electoral System
That Is the Additional Member System (AMS)
The
members of Scottish Parliament (MSP) are elected using the Additional Member
System (AMS), which is much more proportionate than the Westminster one. However,
a Scottish voter has two votes and each vote is governed by a different
principle of calculation.
The
constituency vote is the quintessential First-Past-The-Post (FPTP) vote i.e. in
order to be elected as an MSP, the candidate must win 50% + 1 of all the votes
casted. This can mean that a huge number of the electorate (up to 50% - 1
voters) may not actually be represented in the legislature if all members were
to be elected solely on FPTP. (In theory that is how it works although, clearly, with multi-candidate constituencies the % required to win the seat can be smaller.)
The
regional/list vote is the proportional vote i.e. MSPs are elected from the
lists provided by all contesting parties based on the percentages (this is not
particularly 100% accurate and I will clarify later) of votes they have had
received. What the regional/list vote does is that it will augment the
constituency vote in order to give representation to the 50% - 1 voters, via
the aforementioned percentages, thus making the Scottish Parliament much more
proportionate. Crudely speaking, the correlation is that the more constituency
seats a party gains, the less it will gain from the regional ones. The
distribution of the regional/list seats are calculated based on the d’Hondt method.
It
is well known why AMS was chosen as the electoral system for the Scottish
Parliament. Due to the d’Hondt method, it is generally difficult for any party
in the Scottish Parliament to gain a majority (though it may be the biggest
party). This is compounded by the fact that the ratio of constituency seats to
regional/list seats is unequal, the ration being 73:56. Again, if any party
wins a majority of the constituency seats, it will never be able to win a
majority of the regional/list seats (as per the aforementioned correlation).
The unequal ratio will almost automatically ensure that the regional/list seat
gains will always be invariably smaller to the constituency seats. This is to
expressly discourage a majority from being achieved. This subtle stitch-up
remained true until 2011.
Why The Regional/List
Vote Is Much More Important That Voters Believe But Very Much Misunderstood
Let
us attempt to understand and calculate the distribution of the regional/list
seats. Constituency vote can be easily understood as it is governed by FPTP
principle. As it is governed by FPTP principle, the constituency vote has no
bearing on the regional/list vote. Regional/list vote is governed by a totally
different principle in order to achieve proportionality. Figures like the
percentages of votes, actual votes casts etc. are RED HERRING. The only figures that matters are the ACTUAL NUMBERS OF SEATS WON by
parties, as only these will used in the d’Hondt method.
The
same can be said in relation to the regional/list vote. The only figures that
matters are the ACTUAL NUMBERS OF VOTES
WON by parties, as only these will used in the d’Hondt method. The others
are RED HERRING.
The d’Hondt Method
For the
purpose of illustration, the results for the constituency and regional/list
votes for Central Scotland are listed below for our use:
Scottish
Parliament general election, 2011: Central Scotland
|
||||||
Constituency
|
Elected member
|
Result
|
||||
Airdrie and Shotts
|
Alex Neil
|
SNP gain from Labour
|
||||
Coatbridge and Chryston
|
Elaine Smith
|
Labour hold
|
||||
Cumbernauld and Kilsyth
|
Jamie Hepburn
|
SNP gain from Labour
|
||||
East Kilbride
|
Linda Fabiani
|
SNP gain from Labour
|
||||
Falkirk East
|
Angus MacDonald
|
SNP gain from Labour
|
||||
Falkirk West
|
Michael Matheson
|
SNP hold
|
||||
Hamilton, Larkhall and Stonehouse
|
Christina McKelvie
|
SNP gain from Labour
|
||||
Motherwell and Wishaw
|
John Pentland
|
Labour hold
|
||||
Uddingston and Bellshill
|
Michael McMahon
|
Labour hold
|
Scottish parliamentary
election, 2011: Central Scotland
|
|||||||
Party
|
Elected candidates
|
Seats
|
+/−
|
Votes
|
%
|
+/−%
|
|
SNP
|
Richard Lyle
John Wilson Claire Adamson |
3
|
−2
|
108,261
|
46.4%
|
+15.5%
|
|
Labour
|
Siobhan McMahon
Mark Griffin Margaret McCulloch |
3
|
+3
|
82,459
|
35.3%
|
−4.6%
|
|
Conservative
|
Margaret Mitchell
|
1
|
±0
|
14,870
|
6.4%
|
−1.9%
|
|
Liberal Democrats
|
0
|
−1
|
3,318
|
1.4%
|
−3.8%
|
The
d’Hondt method used in calculating the allocation of regional list seats is as
follows:
Quot = V divided by S + 1
where:
·
quot is the
figures in the schedule derived from the d’Hondt method
·
V is the total number of votes that
the party received in the regional/list vote, and
·
s is the number of constituency seats
that the party has won.
The
total votes cast for each party in the electoral district is divided, first by
1, then by 2, then 3, right up to the total number of seats to be allocated for
the regional/list seats i.e. seven
(7).
Party
|
/1
|
/2
|
/3
|
/4
|
/5
|
/6
|
/7
|
SNP (s=6)
|
15,465
|
13,533
|
12,029
|
10,826
|
9842
|
9,021
|
8,328
|
LAB (s=3)
|
20,615
|
16,492
|
13,743
|
11,780
|
10,307
|
9,612
|
8,246
|
CON (s=0)
|
14,870
|
7,435
|
4,957
|
3,718
|
2,974
|
2,478
|
2,124
|
LIB (s=0)
|
3,318
|
1,654
|
1,106
|
830
|
664
|
553
|
474
|
The
regional/list seats will be allocated to the seven highest figures derived from
the calculations as highlighted. For a clearer understanding of the
significance of these figures, the table below ranks the priority of seats in
terms of votes (from highest to lowest):
Seat No
|
Party
|
Votes
|
1
|
LAB
|
20,615
|
2
|
LAB
|
16,492
|
3
|
SNP
|
15,465
|
4
|
CON
|
14,870
|
5
|
LAB
|
13,743
|
6
|
SNP
|
13,533
|
7
|
SNP
|
12,029
|
To
achieve the finality of seat distribution, several factors must be fulfilled;
a) number of constituency seats must be precisely known (which MAY be predicted from the polls
at best) and b) number of actual votes casted in the regional/list vote must be
precisely known (IMPOSSIBLE
until on the election day itself). Most tactical voters are harping on the
regional/list votes. The above example shows the non-feasibility and
improbability of the proposition to vote tactically.
I cannot fully emphasise how important
it is for voters to vote for the parties/manifestoes they believe in. Scottish parliamentary
election employs a sophisticated electoral system and a lot of Scots do not
fully grasp this sophistication. Voters must understand what are the relevant
numbers being used in the d’Hondt method and the red herrings. Minute
difference in numbers and calculations can have big impacts. In an ideal
electoral system, it would be fully proportionate and seats would be allocated
solely on the percentages of votes cast. This is not the case with the
Scottish Parliament.
Vote
Smartly
Tactical voting is cynical and
destructive. The idea of a Labour voter voting for a Tory candidate is
dumbfounding. The total conflict of ideology is astounding. The result would be
self-harming, literally. Each vote should be based on an informed decision.
This allows voters to flexible and chooses their MSPs sensibly.
IN
SHORT, VOTERS SHOULD VOTE FOR WHAT THEY BELIEVE TO BE IN THEIR BEST INTEREST.
I will highlight several important
reasons on why voters should not vote tactically in the 2016 Scottish
Parliamentary election. The reasons are as follows:
1. For SNP party members/voters, we are
where we are because we keep voting for the SNP. The 2011 majority, the
Independence Referendum, the best Westminster election results and the
political awakening of the Scots, among others, were achieved because of this.
The end game has and will always be the independence of Scotland. Only the SNP
remains steadfast in this. Remember we are only halfway through; Labour
Fortress Glasgow has yet to be won. We cannot deviate from this purpose. We
have to keep voting for SNP until independence is achieved and/or a better
proportionate representative electoral system is devised.
2. Tactical voting is only possible when
the choice is binary-like (for example the SNP versus one of the Unionist
parties). The outcome can be relatively predicted if the electoral system is
based on FPTP. The 2015 UK general election illustrated this perfectly. The SNP
won 56 seats because of the solid voting by SNP members/voters/Yes voters
(45%). The SNPOut campaigned failed
because for the same reason. The Unionist/No voters (55%) failed to consolidate
behind one of the Unionist candidates. This was also particularly true in the
election of David Mundell. SNP members/voters/Yes voters (45%) failed to consolidate
behind SNP’s Emma Harper and some blamed Green voters for splitting the Yes
vote. If the SNP have had asked the Greens to vote tactically for Emma Harper,
it is a bit hypocritical for the SNP now to ask the Scottish Green Party to
stop asking SNP members from tactically vote from them in the 2016 Scottish
Parliament election.
Polls are merely snapshots of what the
electorate thinking and cannot accurately predict the outcome that is needed to
vote tactically in a complicated electoral system such as AMS. There will
always be core voters that will vote for their parties regardless. This is
especially dangerous when dealing with Scottish Tories. They believe that they
are experiencing a (self-perceived?) political renaissance in Scotland. I
believe the Scottish Tories will go all out in the 2016 Scottish Election and
will try to position itself as the main opposition in the Scottish Parliament. If
the calculation is a bit skewed, not only the Scottish Greens will fail to win
the regional/list seats, Scottish Labour or Tories will end up with additional
MSPs.
Another quirk of tactical voting is as
such; it is used TO VOTE OUT NOT VOTE
IN. Tactical voting is feasible when the choice is binary-like. Under
AMS, the equation is already SNP+LAB+CON+LIB. Now we are trying to get GR in it.
Not only it is not binary-like, we are actually trying to expand the equation!
The calculations will be very difficult at the very least and possibilities of
distribution of seats are infinite.
3. Under AMS, Unionist Party will always
be represented in the Scottish Parliament. This must be accepted. The caveat in
the 2011 Scottish Parliamentary election is that only 50% of the electorate
turned out to vote. I believe the recent poll safely gauge the percentage of
the core Unionist votes. This means another 15-30% of the electorate may be
voting in the 2016 Scottish Parliament election this and still open to
persuasion by any political party (on the assumption that the turnout will be
around 65-80%). For me, it is laziness if Scottish Greens would want to win
just by riding on the back of the SNP. Voters should for vote Scottish Greens
on their merit. All parties must start registration of voters drive and get as
many voters to turn out on 5 May 2016. On the issue of 16 & 17 year-old
voters, all parties must be vigilant and be prepared to do mass registration.
4. Scottish Green Party has different (Green)
political priorities than the SNP. Unless and until the Scottish Greens are
explicitly committed to Independence cause, please keep voting the SNP in both
votes in order to ensure an SNP majority. This is most paramount. Vote
differently if you think the non-SNP candidate/manifestoes is worth voting for
(for me I would only vote for Scottish Greens if Andy Wightman [go Andy!] is
standing in my constituency). If not, any vote for a party other than the SNP
will serve to weaken the Independence cause (Refer again to Reason No 1).
5. Policy areas worth considering when
casting your vote are land reform, local government, child care, public
transportation (railways in particular), telecommunications and education. Any
party promoting good policies on these areas are worth your votes. These policies,
in my opinion, will strengthen and hasten the Independence cause.
Conclusion
The only way to gauge a party’s strength
vis-à-vis the electorate is for all voters to vote for the parties they believe
in. Tactical voting is almost impossible and inevitably self-defeating. In
order to vote in Scottish Greens, the calculations (i.e. numbers of
constituency seats and actual votes casted in the regional/list vote) must be
precise and exact. Basing the calculations on the 9 June TNS Poll is foolish,
misleading and not feasible at all.
One week is a long time in politics,
what more a year. Polls will change; it may not even be correct. Many factors
discussed in this post and other blogs have highlighted the uncertainty of
tactical voting. Even the seemingly straightforward SNPOut campaign cannot and
did not get it right.
The best advice I can give: VOTE SNP/SNP OR WHATEVER PARTY YOU
BELIEVE IN.
(p/s: I wish we had had elected Emma
Harper.)
* Some segments of the post were copied in toto from Wikipedia.